Phone: 454-4774; FAX: (808) 454-4776;
E-Mail: CLEAR; or to return to CLEAR's
Home Page
by Lawrence W. Boyd, Ph. D.
Labor Economist
Does the Jones Act cost every Hawai'i household three thousand dollars?
This is the number typically cited by the news media and those who oppose the Jones Act. The
Jones Act refers to a series of laws enacted in the 1920s which among other things require that
American owned ships transport goods between American ports. These laws, called cabotage
laws, have been enacted by forty-five countries. Opponents of the law in the United States range
from conservative free marketers to groups representing foreign shipping interests.
The theoretical reasoning behind the opposition to the Jones Act is that it is a
restraint of free trade between nations. Free trade makes possible the development of a truly
international division of labor which in turn allows countries to specialize in doing what they do
best. Countries can have a "comparative advantage" in the production of certain goods and
services. By specializing in the production of those goods which can be produced best in a given
country and trading for those goods it is not so good at producing individual country's economies
can generate far higher incomes and living standards than if those countries did not trade.
Because the Jones Act restricts trade between points within the United States opponents argue
that it is a restriction of free trade and is equivalent to a tariff on goods and services Hawai'i
brings in from the mainland. (A tariff is a tax levied on imported goods).
Those who defend the Jones Act argue that it is the only way that United State's
environmental, labor and other laws can be enforced within American waters. These laws range
from restrictions on trash dumping to ship designs which limit oil spills to minimum wage laws.
Second that there are national security reasons for maintaining a domestic merchant marine
capable of transporting military cargo during national emergencies. They also argue that the costs
of the Jones Act compared to the benefits are not high.
The question of how much the Jones Act costs is central to the argument of both opponents and proponents of the Jones Act. Below I analyze the claims of those in Hawai'i who oppose the Jones act.
Three-thousand Dollars per Household?
Those who oppose the Jones Act, such as the Hawai'i Shippers Council, have
distributed the table I have reproduced below. (This is taken from a packet handed out at
Legislative hearings and by State Senator Whitney Anderson). I have condensed some of the
description in order to save space.
Differential between existing freight rates and the world price-estimated | |
Common Carrier/Liner Segment | |
30% differential on total freights of $650 million | $201.5 |
Non-liner/Tramp Cargo Segments | 50% differential on total freights of $100 million | $50.0 |
Subtotal: Estimated Freight Penalty (in millions) | $251.5 |
Economic multiplier for ocean freight** | x 2.5 |
Subtotal (in millions) | $628.75 |
Annual Lost Economic Activity-Estimate in millions | $371.25 |
Total Estimated Costs (in millions) | $1,000.00 |
**Annual Multiplied Economic Burden-Estimated
The estimated direct, indirect and induced effects as computed by Hawai'i State's economic multiplier for ocean freight.
The total estimate of one billion is then divided by the numbers of households to
arrive at a cost for the Jones Act of three-thousand dollars per household. This number is inflated
since it assumes 333,333 Hawaiian households rather than the actual number of 420,748 in 1995
as the divisor.
While one could dispute the numbers concerning the 30% to 50% price
differential on freight rates and lost economic activity, this is not the problem with the table
above. One cannot use the Hawai'i State's economic multiplier for ocean freight to estimate "the
direct, indirect and induced effects" of the Jones Act. In fact the Hawai'i State multiplier can be
used to estimate the impact of the Jones Act, but it is in precisely the opposite manner used in the
table above. Rather than adding the number from the economic multiplier it should have been
subtracted from the total.
How to Correctly Estimate the Overall Effect of the Jones Act
Impact analysis, which is what the state's input-output model is typically used
for, "measures the change in output (production), employment, and income in all industries of the
econnomy as a consequence of a change in the final demand of a particular industry" (1987
Input-Output Tables for Hawai'i State, November 4, 1994, p. 19). Jones Act opponents
mistakenly use this when they multiply the "freight penalty" above by 2.5. The number
represents the reduction in final demand throughout the State. For example the $251.1 million
dollars saved by consumers of shipping must be subtracted from ocean freight in Hawai'i. It
basically disappears from the economy, and the Hawaiian shipping industry. The Hawai'i State
input-output model is set up to provide an estimate of what happens when there is a net increase
or outflow of revenue from a particular industry such as ocean freight. Thus the $251.1 should be
multiplied by the 2.5 multiplier but the $628.75 million dollars represents the income lost to the
state as a result of abolition of the Jones Act from all industries.
Where does the $251.5 million go? Because this represents money which
shippers would have paid but no longer pay it will be pocketed by consumers of ocean transport.
Some of this savings will go directly to consumers like service personnel who ship cars and
household items when they move to Hawai'i. The bulk however probably would go to firms who
use ocean shipping to transport goods for resale in Hawai'i.
If we could indeed use the input-output tables to reallocate revenue from one industry to another,
then the final gain, would be the addition of the $371.5 million listed in the table above. This
means the net estimated loss to the Hawaiian economy from abolition of the Jones Act would
be $257 million in output. Table 2 below summarizes these findings.
Table 2: Corrected Estimate of the Impact of Repeal of the Jones Act
Gain to Consumers of Ocean Shipping (millions of dollars) | $251.1 |
Multiplier | x1.47 |
Total | $371.25 |
Direct Loss to Ocean Shipping | $251.1 |
Multiplier | x2.5 |
Total | $628.5 |
Gain | $371.25 | Loss | -$628.5 |
Total | -257.25 |
Why are these results so different? Often when highly charged debates take place you occasionally see "dueling experts" for both sides who provide different results because they are paid or committed to one side or the other. This is not the case here. This research is a spin off of a larger research project where I am trying to determine the degree to which competition exists in the Hawaiian shipping trade. Neither the Center for Labor Education and Research nor myself have received any financial support for this effort. What has happened here is the opponents have triple counted. First they did not subtract the loss to the ocean shipping industry, second they multiplied the loss by the state's multiplier and added that to the total, third they added the gains from the reduction in freight charges to the previous totals. This is not a disagreement over numbers, it represents an incorrect use by Jones act opponents of the State's Input-Output Economic Model.
Some Further Considerations
I have not been able to confirm the actual numbers used by opponents of the
Jones in evaluating its effect. They seem to be related to a report by the International Trade
Commission (ITC) released in 1991 which had a low estimate of the economic impact of the
Jones Act on the U. S. economy of approximately $4 billion and a high of almost $10 billion.
These estimates were revised by the ITC in 1993 to "approximately $3.1 billion" and in 1995 to
"2.8" billion." The numbers above appear to be high numbers which would in turn effect the
overall loss or gain to the Hawaiian economy.
Second, the ITC used a much more appropriate theory in evaluating the impact
of the Jones Act and this has come across in garbled form when used here in Hawai'i by Jones
Act opponents. If the Jones Act restricts competition, it leads to higher prices for ocean shipping.
Because there are some consumers who are willing to pay this higher price a reduction will
increase their welfare. Using the $251.1 million number above one can say this is the amount by
which their welfare will increase through the repeal of the Jones Act. Per household this works
out to a cost of $596.44 (when using correct number of households as denominator) not $3,000.
It should also be noted that the 30 and 50 percent shipping cost differential seems to be an
unreasonably high estimate.
Finally in terms of the losses to the Hawaiian economy the above estimate is
probably an underestimate. I have assumed that there will be no further loss beyond the $250
million dollars to foreign carriers. This is not a very reasonable assumption. For example Sealand
and Matson could register their ships in a foreign country in order to avoid the loss of business.
This means they would not have to comply with labor and environmental regulations. It would
also mean a further gross reduction in terms of the economic loss to Hawai'i. Or we could assume
that the remaining shipping will be taken over by foreign carriers. The shipping revenue after the
Jones Act Repeal would be about $500 million. If 20 percent were taken over by foreign carriers
($100 million) then the gross loss would be an additional $250 million in output. If it all went to
foreign carriers the gross loss would be $1.5 billion in output.
In summary, using Jones Act opponents' numbers, there would be a net loss of $257.25 million to $1.5 billion in output per year in Hawai'i, or a loss ranging from $611 to to $3,563 per household if the Jones Act were repealed. The number of jobs lost in ocean shipping ranges from a low of 5,675 to a high of 17,025. This compares with a total loss of jobs in the Hawaiian economy of approximately 13,000 since 1991. The loss in personal income would range from a low of $157,750,000 to a high of $473,250,000.
In conclusion, the Jones Act opponents are simply misusing the State's input-output tables. Though I have used their own numbers in this analysis, they too appear suspect. For example, they appear to use an incorrect number of households in order to arrive at the $3,000 per household number. None of the material put out by the Jones Act opponents details job loss, as I have done above. And they appear to be confused when it comes to defining "economic activity." Economic activity can mean output by various industries, and this appears to be what they mean when they use a multiplier of 2.5. But output does not translate directly into income. There is a different multiplier for that. Thus the per capita income lost from repeal of the Jones Act would range from -$37.50 per household to -$1,124 as results from a decline in the ocean shipping industry.
For more information on this project, call, write or E-Mail Dr. Lawrence W. Boyd, Jr. at:
CLEAR University of Hawai'i - West O'ahu 96-043 Ala 'Ike, Bldg. 400 Pearl City, HI 96782-3366 phone: (808) 454-4774; FAX: (808) 454-4776 E-Mail: lboyd@hawaii.edu |